Israeli Economists’ Dangerous Minds
In discussions of the Israeli government’s economic program in various forums in the economics department at Ben-Gurion University of the Negev, the students expressed firm opinions against the poor who don’t work, against the welfare state and against the public sector. In a conversation with the professors, the students said, “What do you want? We learned these things from you.”
Studies carried out at universities in the United States found that students of economics are more selfish than their classmates. In the famous “ultimatum game” experiment, one of the students, “the allocator,” is given the opportunity to decide how to divide a certain sum of money between himself and another student, who is also participating in the experiment. If the second student, “the recipient,” agrees to the allocation — it is carried out. If not, they both receive nothing. If both players are rational, the allocator will offer an amount that will be agreeable to the recipient.
Surprisingly, in such experiments, it has been found that the fair division of 50-50 is most common, and that the allocator doesn’t exploit his preferential status. But among economics majors, it is statistically clear that the allocator consistently receives more than in other disciplines.
The real test of economics students comes in the introductory course on economics. Many economists have told me that the most important part of their studies was the introduction to economics. The course was structured by the father of economic teaching and research in Israel, Dan Patinkin. The introduction to microeconomics, which deals with the operation and efficiency of markets, has remained almost unchanged after decades of teaching. I learned it as a freshman in 1966 and have taught it many times since then. With the aid of a series of economic models, the course succeeds in causing its graduates to internalize open and latent messages.
The open messages: Free competition in the market is optimal, and there is no need for intervention. There is room for government activity in the economy only when there are failures in the market. The latent messages: The course discusses “intervention of the government in the free market”; In other words, the government undermines individual freedoms. An analysis of taxes deals only with how taxes interfere with market activity, and there isn’t a word about the necessary activity that the taxes fund. Taxing only causes damage. Market failures are only in marginal industries, like air pollution, and therefore the government has to be small.
These messages show that the market is good and efficient, and government is superfluous and inefficient. The messages are reinforced in the study of macroeconomics during the second year. Is it any wonder that our students think that there is nothing as good as the market, and nothing as bad as the public sector, with the logical conclusion that there is nothing better than privatizing the public sector?
Economics research during the past 30 years has led to a better understanding of the reasons for market efficiency. The research has taught us that what brings about efficiency in the competitive market is not a mystical element of freedom from government intervention, but the incentives that competition brings with it. From this we can conclude that with proper planning of incentives, the public sector can operate efficiently, whereas with distorted incentives, the private sector will operate inefficiently.
A good example is Bezeq, a government telephone company that provides incentives for its technicians by payment for each installation of a new telephone. In the 1980s there was no system of incentives, and four Bezeq workers would come to install a telephone: One worked and three drank coffee. Now one worker comes, and he doesn’t stop running. On the other hand, giving incentives to directors of business corporations in America in the form of huge bonuses related to the profits of the company they directed led to false accounting and the fall of Enron.
The introduction to economics course and the rest of bachelor’s degree studies in economics must undergo a profound change in order to become more balanced and relevant to the modern economy. It’s our job, as professors of economics.
The typical training of those who determine economic policy in Israel is a bachelor’s degree in economics and a master’s degree in administration. There is a need for a basic change in this training and in the public discourse in order to stop the deterioration of the public sector and the damage to its professionalism.
If not, elementary and secondary education will not recover from their sad state, and the universities will find themselves in a deep financial crisis. The relative advantage of the State of Israel — its human capital — will disappear. Institutions such as the National Insurance Institute and the Bank of Israel will lose professionals to the private sector, and Israel’s good standing in international bodies will become eroded. And the quality of life in Israel, instead of advancing toward that of the West, will deteriorate to the level of the Third World.
Avia Spivak is the deputy governor of the Bank of Israel and a lecturer in economics at Ben-Gurion University of the Negev. This article originally appeared in Ha’aretz, whose Web site is www.haaretzdaily.com.
A message from our CEO & publisher Rachel Fishman Feddersen
I hope you appreciated this article. Before you go, I’d like to ask you to please support the Forward’s award-winning, nonprofit journalism during this critical time.
We’ve set a goal to raise $260,000 by December 31. That’s an ambitious goal, but one that will give us the resources we need to invest in the high quality news, opinion, analysis and cultural coverage that isn’t available anywhere else.
If you feel inspired to make an impact, now is the time to give something back. Join us as a member at your most generous level.
— Rachel Fishman Feddersen, Publisher and CEO